top of page

Understanding Payment for Environmental Services


What is Payment for Environmental Services [13]


Payment for Environmental Services (PES) was the heart of my graduation thesis, a complex exploration that transformed my understanding of environmental conservation, economic mechanisms, and the intricate relationships between human societies and natural ecosystems. My scholarly pursuit was driven by a fundamental question: How can we create economic frameworks that value and protect our planet's most critical resources? PES emerged as a fascinating response to this challenge, offering a nuanced approach that goes far beyond traditional conservation strategies.

What is PES?

Ecosystem services represent the multifaceted benefits that humans derive from nature's intricate systems [1][2]. Traditionally viewed as free public goods, these services have been largely undervalued and consequently overexploited. Payment for Ecosystem Services proposes a radical reimagining of this dynamic, transforming environmental services from seemingly infinite resources into carefully valued economic commodities [3][4].

The conceptual origins of PES can be traced to a fundamental economic insight: what is not monetized is often not protected. By creating a market mechanism that assigns economic value to environmental services, PES aims to align economic interests with ecological preservation. This approach represents a pragmatic response to the seemingly irreconcilable tension between economic development and environmental conservation.

Wunder provided the first definition of PES, establishing a crucial theoretical foundation for understanding PES. He described it as "a voluntary transaction where a well-defined ES (or land-use likely to secure that service) is being bought by a buyer from a provider, if and only if the provider secures ES provision (conditionality)" [5]. Wunder identified four primary ecosystem services central to this approach: carbon sequestration and storage, biodiversity protection, watershed protection, and landscape beauty.

However, the theoretical landscape of PES is not without complexity. Scholarly critique has emerged, challenging Wunder's definition as overly narrow and deeply rooted in neoliberal economic thinking. Real-world implementation has revealed a far more nuanced approach to ecosystem service valuation [6].

The theoretical complexity of PES extends beyond simple economic transactional models. Bennett and Gosnell propose a sophisticated framework that fundamentally reframes our understanding of ecosystem service payments. They conceptualize PES not as a straightforward market exchange but as "an interaction among actors embedded within a defined social–ecological system in which buyers invest in resource units with the intent of enhancing or maintaining the delivery of beneficial ecosystem services from the resource system" [7].

This definition represents a significant advancement in PES theory. Unlike more mechanistic approaches, Bennett and Gosnell's framework acknowledges the intricate social and ecological networks within which these transactions occur. It shifts the perspective from a purely economic interaction to a complex, multidimensional engagement that recognizes the interconnected nature of human and ecological systems.

This theoretical framework guided my research on mangrove Payment for Environmental Services in Ca Mau, Vietnam. The research uncovered intricate connections between local communities and their natural environments. I also explored the stakeholder dynamics in Ca Mau—involving local farmers, government agencies, and international organization—provided a compelling microcosm of the global challenges in ecosystem service management. In future posts, I will share the detailed insights from this research, offering a deeper understanding of these complex interactions.

PES in a “Policy Mix”

The concept of a "policy mix" provides additional context for understanding PES. Emerging from economic policy literature of the 1960s and gaining prominence in biodiversity conservation research since the 1990s, this approach conceptualizes environmental management as a strategic combination of policy instruments [8][9]. In this framework, PES is not a standalone solution but a sophisticated component of a broader environmental management strategy.

PES demonstrates remarkable versatility in policy implementation. It serves multiple critical functions, including:

  • Providing economic incentives for environmental conservation

  • Augmenting existing legal regulations through compensation mechanisms

  • Enhancing the effectiveness of potentially weak environmental protection laws

  • Creating additional income streams for local communities

Yet, the approach is not without significant challenges. Scholarly research has highlighted potential limitations and unintended consequences. Some researchers argue that PES should maintain a focused objective of ecosystem service delivery, warning that broader social goals might compromise its core environmental mission [10].

Empirical research offers nuanced insights into these challenges. A comprehensive meta-analysis of watershed service payments revealed potential complications when multiple objectives are introduced. Environmental conservation goals can be inadvertently undermined by simultaneous efforts to address poverty alleviation [11]. Furthermore, PES interventions may have unintended consequences for local livelihoods, potentially disrupting existing economic activities [12].

These findings underscore the intricate and multifaceted nature of environmental economic mechanisms. Payment for Ecosystem Services (PES) is not a one-size-fits-all solution; its success hinges on thoughtful design, ongoing evaluation, and a deep understanding of local ecological and economic contexts. By creating economic incentives that reflect the intrinsic value of ecosystem services, PES offers a pragmatic approach to aligning economic priorities with environmental conservation. However, its implementation is fraught with challenges, requiring persistent learning, adaptive strategies, and critical scrutiny.

In the next post, we will explore the global implementation of PES and examine the conditions necessary for its effective adoption across diverse settings.


References

  1. Boyd, J. and Banzhaf, S. (2007) ‘What are ecosystem services? The need for standardized environmental accounting units’, Ecological Economics, 63(2–3), pp. 616–626.

  2. García-Llorente, M. et al. (2012) ‘The role of multi-functionality in social preferences toward semi-arid rural landscapes: an ecosystem service approach’, Environmental Science & Policy, 19, pp. 136–146.

  3. Nguyen, T.Q., Huynh, N.T. and Hsu, W.-K.K. (2021) ‘Estimate the Impact of Payments for Environmental Services on Local Livelihoods and Environment: An Application of Propensity Scores’, SAGE Open, 11(3), p. 21582440211040774. https://doi.org/10.1177/21582440211040774.

  4. Do, T.H., Patton, I. and Catacutan, D. (2022) ‘Towards pro-poor and voluntary PES: assessment of willingness to pay and willingness to accept PES contract in central Vietnam’, Journal of Land Use Science, 17(1), pp. 505–522. https://doi.org/10.1080/1747423X.2022.2127953.

  5. Wunder, S. (2005). Payments for environmental services: some nuts and bolts (Vol. 42, pp. 1-32). Bogor: CIFOR.

  6. Salzman, J., et al. (2018) 'The global status and trends of payments for ecosystem services', Nature Sustainability, 1(3), pp. 136–144.

  7. Bennett, D.E. and Gosnell, H. (2015) ‘Integrating multiple perspectives on payments for ecosystem services through a social–ecological systems framework’, Ecological Economics, 116, pp. 172–181. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2015.04.019.

  8. Barton, D.N. et al. (2017) ‘Payments for Ecosystem Services as a Policy Mix: Demonstrating the institutional analysis and development framework on conservation policy instruments’, Environmental Policy and Governance, 27(5), pp. 404–421.

  9. Izquierdo‐Tort, S. (2020) ‘Payments for ecosystem services and conditional cash transfers in a policy mix: Microlevel interactions in Selva Lacandona, Mexico’, Environmental Policy and Governance, 30(1), pp. 29–45. https://doi.org/10.1002/eet.1876.

  10. Kinzig, A.P. et al. (2011) ‘Paying for Ecosystem Services—Promise and Peril’, Science, 334(6056), pp. 603–604. https://doi.org/10.1126/science.1210297.

  11. Bouma, J.A. et al. (2019) ‘Policy mix: mess or merit?’, Journal of Environmental Economics and Policy, 8(1), pp. 32–47. https://doi.org/10.1080/21606544.2018.1494636.

  12. Moros, L., Vélez, M. A., & Corbera, E. (2019). Payments for ecosystem services and motivational crowding in Colombia's Amazon Piedmont. Ecological Economics, 156, 468–488.

  13. Besacier, C., Garrett, L., Iweins, M., & Shames, S. (2021). Local financing mechanisms for forest and landscape restoration: A review of local-level investment mechanisms.

Comments


bottom of page